Monday, October 11, 2010

Perlu tahu sejarah pembangunan institusi baitulmal dalam Islam....


Salam semua.....


Maklumat ini penting untuk dikongsi bersama..ia penting juga. Lihat fatwa Umar al Khattab dihujung artikel ini..pemberian pencen kepada bukan Islam....


Bayt al-mal is an Arabic term that is translated as “House of Money” or “House of Wealth.” Historically, it was a financial institution responsible for the administration oftaxes in Islamic states, particularly in the early Islamic Caliphate. It served as a royal treasury for the caliphs and sultans, managing personal finances and government expenditures. Further, it administered distributions of zakah revenues for public works. Modern Islamic economists deem the institutional framework appropriate for contemporary Islamic societies.
History
Bayt al-mal was the department that dealt with the revenues and all other economical matters of the state. In the time of Muhammad there was no permanent Bait-ul-Mal or public treasury. Whatever revenues or other amounts were received were distributed immediately. There were no salaries to be paid, and there was no state expenditure. Hence the need for the treasury at public level was not felt. In the time of Abu Bakr as well there was not treasury. Abu Bakr earmarked a house where all money was kept on receipt. As all money was distributed immediately the treasury generally remained locked up. At the time of the death of Abu Bakr there was only one dirham in the public treasury.
Establishment of Bait-ul-Maal
In the time of Umar things changed. With the extension in conquests money came in larger quantities, Umar also allowed salaries to men fighting in the armyAbu Huraira who was the Governor of Bahrain sent a revenue of five hundred thousanddirhams. Umar summoned a meeting of his Consultative Assembly and sought the opinion of the Companions about the disposal of the money. Uthman ibn Affanadvised that the amount should be kept for future needs. Walid bin Hisham suggested that like the Byzantines separate departments of Treasury and Accounts should be set up.
After consulting the Companions Umar decided to establish the Central Treasury atMadinah. Abdullah bin Arqam was appointed as the Treasury Officer. He was assisted by Abdur Rahman bin Awf and Muiqib. A separate Accounts Department was also set up and it was required to maintain record of all that was spent. Later provincial treasuries were set up in the provinces. After meeting the local expenditure the provincial treasuries were required to remit the surplus amount to the central treasury at Madinah. According to Yaqubi the salaries and stipends charged to the central treasury amounted to over 30 million dirhams.


The coins were of Persian origin, and had an image of the last Persian emperor, Muslim added the sentence Bismillah to it.
A separate building was constructed for the royal treasury by the name bait ul maal, which in large cities was guarded by as many as 400 guards. In most of the historical accounts, it states that among the Rashidun caliphsUthman ibn Affan was first to struck the coins, some accounts however states that Umar was first to do so. When Persia was conquered three types of coins were current in the conquered territories, namely Baghli of 8 dang; Tabari of 4 dang; and Maghribi of 3 dangUmar( according to some accounts Uthman ) made an innovation and struck an Islamic dirham of 6 dang.
Welfare state
The concepts of welfare and pension were introduced in early Islamic law as forms of Zakat (charity), one of the Five Pillars of Islam, under the Rashidun Caliphate in the 7th century. This practiced continued well into the Abbasid era of the Caliphate. The taxes (including Zakat and Jizya) collected in the treasury of an Islamicgovernment were used to provide income for the needy, including the poorelderly,orphanswidows, and the disabled. According to the Islamic jurist Al-Ghazali(Algazel, 1058–1111), the government was also expected to stockpile food supplies in every region in case a disaster or famine occurred. The Caliphate can thus be considered the world’s first major welfare state.[1][2]
During the Rashidun Caliphate, various welfare programs were introduced by CaliphUmar. In his time, equality was extended to all citizens, even to the caliph himself, as Umar believed that “no one, no matter how important, should live in a way that would distinguish him from the rest of the people.” Umar himself lived “a simple life and detached himself from any of the worldly luxuries,” like how he often wore “worn-out shoes and was usually clad in patched-up garments,” or how he would sleep “on the bare floor of the mosque.” Limitations on wealth were also set for governors and officials, who would often be “dismissed if they showed any outward signs of pride or wealth which might distinguish them from the people.” This was an early attempt at erasing “class distinctions which might inevitably lead to conflict.” Umar also made sure that the public treasury was not wasted on “unnecessary luxuries” as he believed that “the money would be better spent if it went towards the welfare of the people rather than towards lifeless bricks.”[2]
Umar’s innovative welfare reforms during the Rashidun Caliphate included the introduction of social security. This included unemployment insurance, which did not appear in the Western world until the 19th century. In the Rashidun Caliphate, whenever citizens were injured or lost their ability to work, it became the state’s responsibility to make sure that their minimum needs were met, with the unemployed and their families receiving an allowance from the public treasury.[2] Retirementpensions were provided to elderly people,[1] who had retired and could “count on receiving a stipend from the public treasury.” Babies who were abandoned were also taken care of, with one hundred dirhams spent annually on each orphan’s development. Umar also introduced the concept of public trusteeship and public ownership when he implemented the Waqf, or charitable trust, system, which transferred “wealth from the individual or the few to a social collective ownership,” in order to provide “services to the community at large.” For example, Umar brought land from the Banu Harithah and converted it into a charitable trust, which meant that “profit and produce from the land went towards benefiting the poor, slaves, and travelers.”[2]
During the great famine of 18 AH (638 CE), Umar introduced further reforms, such as the introduction of food rationing using coupons, which were given to those in need and could be exchanged for wheat and flour. Another innovative concept that was introduced was that of a poverty threshold, with efforts made to ensure a minimum standard of living, making sure that no citizien across the empire would suffer from hunger. In order to determine the poverty line, Umar ordered anexperiment to test how many seers of flour would be required to feed a person for a month. He found that 25 seers of flour could feed 30 people, and so he concluded that 50 seers of flour would be sufficient to feed a person for a month. As a result, he ordered that the poor each receive a food ration of fifty seers of flour per month. In addition, the poor and disabled were guaranteed cash stipends. However, in order to avoid some citizens taking advantage of government services, “begging and laziness were not tolerated” and “those who received government benefits were expected to be contributing members in the community.”[2]
Further reforms later took place under the Umayyad Caliphate. Registered soldiers who were disabled in service received an invalidity pension, while similar provisions were made for the disabled and poor in general. Caliph Al-Walid I assigned payments and services to the needy, which included money for the poor, guides for the blind, and servants for the crippled, and pensions for all disabled people so that they would never need to beg. The caliphs Al-Walid II and Umar ibn Abdul-Azizsupplied money and clothes to the blind and crippled, as well as servants for the latter. This continued with the Abbasid caliph Al-Mahdi.[3] Tahir ibn Husayn, governor of the Khurasan province of the Abbasid Caliphate, states in a letter to his son that pensions from the treasury should be provided to the blind, to look after the poor and destitute in general, to make sure not to overlook victims of oppression who are unable to complain and are ignorant of how to claim their rights, and that pensions should be assigned to victims of calamities and the widows and orphans they leave behind. The “ideal city” described by the Islamic philosophersAl-Farabiand Avicenna, also assigns funds to the disabled.[4]
When communities were striken by famine, rulers would often support them though measures such as the remission of taxes, importation of food, and charitable payments, ensuring that everyone had enough to eat. However, private charity through the Waqf trust institution often played a greater role in the alleviation of famines than government measures did.[5] From the 9th century, funds from the treasury were also used towards the Waqf (charitable trusts) for the purpose of building and supporting public institutions, often Madrassah educational institutions and Bimaristan hospitals.[6]
Treatment of conquered peoples
Caliph Umar was the first Caliph to provide Allowance to non-Muslims, or Dhimmi, after they reached old age. The very first Non-Muslim to receive pension from the Rashidun Administration was a Jew from the following documented record:
Once Caliph Omar was in the streets of Madina when he saw a man begging. He went to him and asked him; “why are you begging? Are you not receiving maintenance (allowance) from Bait al-mal”. The man replied; “I am a Jew and I am doing this so that I can pay the Jizya”. Hearing this the Caliph Omar took him by his hand to the Bait al-mal and decreed “In the name of Allah you pay Jizya all your life and then you get betrayed when you reach old age.” He ordered to provide that man Pension and from that day it was so ordered for all Jews and Christians and others.
This is how non-Muslims were being given relief from Jizya, though Jizya was not abolished.
References
  1. a b Crone, Patricia (2005), Medieval Islamic Political ThoughtEdinburgh University Press, pp. 308–9, ISBN 0748621946
  2. a b c d e Shadi Hamid (August 2003), “An Islamic Alternative? Equality, Redistributive Justice, and the Welfare State in the Caliphate of Umar”,Renaissance: Monthly Islamic Journal 13 (8)  (see online)
  3. ^ Crone, Patricia (2005), Medieval Islamic Political ThoughtEdinburgh University Press, p. 307, ISBN 0748621946
  4. ^ Crone, Patricia (2005), Medieval Islamic Political ThoughtEdinburgh University Press, p. 308, ISBN 0748621946
  5. ^ Crone, Patricia (2005), Medieval Islamic Political ThoughtEdinburgh University Press, p. 309, ISBN 0748621946
  6. ^ Crone, Patricia (2005), Medieval Islamic Political ThoughtEdinburgh University Press, pp. 309–10 & 312, ISBN 0748621946
See also

No comments: